Stubborn Attachments and Economic Growth

Stubborn Attachments

I just finished reading Stubborn Attachments by economist Tyler Cowen. I frequent his blog, and read a few other books of his. The topics of his books range widely, from how capitalism supports the arts to how American society has grown to be risk-averse. The insights across his works are novel, but what I most appreciate about his books is that he reinforces his arguments with a variety of quantitative measures. However, what stands out in his latest book is how rigorous his approach is to outlining the ethics that undergird his primary argument, which is that our main priority as a society should be maximizing the rate of sustainable economic growth.

Throughout the book, Cowen builds a moral framework for focusing on economic growth (or maximizing “Wealth Plus”, a more nuanced form of GDP). His argument centers around the fact that economic growth is the most effective way of generating wealth in nations, and that this wealth nurtures a society that respects a “plurality of values”. A plurality of values includes but is not limited to economic freedom for an individual, women’s rights, and improvements in medicine. A metaphor central to the book is that of “Crusonia plants” which, when planted, give fruit “for free”. In his view, economic growth is a Crusonia plant in that, given the right conditions to thrive, it will yield additional benefits to society which are concomitant with that growth.

As a means to realize the benefits of the Crusonia plant that is economic growth, he argues for a low discount time rate when considering future generations. In other words, he contends that we should place people who will be born in the distant future closer in moral terms than we currently do. For their sake, we need to concentrate on making our society more stable, taking environmental issues seriously to avoid catastrophe, and most importantly attending to economic growth.

There are other ethical concerns Cowen contemplates to drive home his point (including a rules-based approach to decision making, a skeptical approach to policy making, reconciling common sense and utilitarian morality, and an appeal to our human reason). However, the overwhelming benefits of economic growth is central to Cowen’s work, so he takes special care in outlining these benefits and elaborating on hypothetical past and future growth scenarios. I decided to give these hypotheticals a deeper look, and to visualize them when possible.

What Does Economic Growth Look Like?

Where We Are and Could Be

Early in the book, Cowen points to a poll conducted by Russ Roberts. He asked journalists how much economic growth there’s been since 1900. The majority said standards of living increased by 50%, while the reality is that (estimated conservatively) US standard of living has increased by a factor of 5 to 7.

Some quick facts from the 1900 United States Census Bureau drive home this reality:

• 95% of US households had 1+ occupants per room, and 23% had 3.5 persons per sleeping room
• 24% of US households had running water, 18% had refrigerators, 12% had gas/electric lighting
• 5% of US households had telephones, none had TV or radio

Today we take for granted that all of these statistics are now over 99%. It’s clear how much more well off we are as consumers. What isn’t captured here is how strenuous jobs were, how poor medical care was, and how little time people had to do what they wished. (These untypical economic measures constitute the “plus” part of the “Wealth Plus” measure that Cowen talks about).

So how did we get to where we are today? Here’s a plot of US growth rates since 1929 (the gdp figures are in billions of chained 2012 dollars):

With some notable dips (in 1932, 1946, and most recently in 2009) the US economy has seen steady positive growth, hovering at 3% YoY growth on average. So…is this good? What if it had been higher? While a single year’s growth may make a small difference, if slow growth continues over a long span of time then there are serious consequences for wellbeing. Cowen claims: “redo U.S. history, but assume the country’s economy had grown one percentage point less each year between 1870 and 1990. In that scenario, the United States of 1990 would be no richer than the Mexico of 1990.” It’s revealing to compare hypotheticals, and to see how much worse off — and also how much better off — we could be at different rates of growth:

What’s striking to me is how much wealthier our economy would be at 5% average annual growth. Our economy would be nearly 4.5 times as big as it is now! What our lives would look now had the economy grown at this rate is hard to envision, given how much the average American life changed since 1929 at our current growth rate. What is easier to envision, however, is how long it would actually take to 3x the size of our economy at different rates of growth:

It is easier now to understand why our GDP would be so much higher at a 5% hypothetical growth rate compared to what it is now. At a 5% growth rate, we would 3x the size of our economy in under 25 years! In contrast, at 2% growth it would take just over 50 years, while at a 1% growth rate it would take over 100 years.

Real Growth Rates, High and Low

While it is enlightening to look at various hypothetical growth rates, it’s equally illuminating to look at different countries’ economies and what kind of story their growth rates reveal. It’s of course tough to compare economies at different stages in their development. A developing economy like India is going to have much more tumultuous rates of growth than a developed economy like Japan. As economies modernize, it becomes harder to maintain the high rates of growth of a country who is just starting down their road to development. Still, it’s interesting to make comparisons to economies that are roughly at the same stage. Here I plot a graph of high-growth nations since 2000, and compare them to the American growth rate in red:

These three countries’ growth rates exhibit all of the turbulence we would expect from developing economies. Many would argue Ethiopia is farther behind the path to development than these other countries, but I wanted to choose an African country that epitomizes the impact of a high growth rate. While we see some precipitous dips (i.e. Ethiopia in 2010), across the board we see unprecedented growth in these countries. If we consider the impact of 5% growth on living standards in our hypothetical example earlier, we begin to understand the astonishing impact of growth that is occurring right now in these nations.

For comparison, I also plotted US growth. Of course, it makes little sense to compare US growth to these economies, given that the US is much farther along in its economic development. It is illuminating, however, to compare US growth to other economically developed nations:

We quickly see a different growth story for these nations. As I mentioned earlier, the historic US growth rate has hovered at 3%. However, these countries emphasize the fact that we cannot take economic growth in the developed world for granted. Especially in the decade following the financial collapse, the British, French, and Japanese economies have exhibited declines in their growth rates, in contrast to the United States economy which has resumed modest growth levels after 2009. While the 5% growth level in the hypothetical scenario—brought to life by countries like India, China, and Ethiopia—captivates us in terms of its potential for the quality of human life in those nations, the specter of 1% growth level—suggested by the countries in the graph above—should haunt developed nations and compel them not to sit on their laurels.

I’d like to paint one more picture of growth. After introducing his “Principle of Growth”, which is that we should maximize our rate of sustainable growth, Cowen asserts that this principle was unquestionably applied once in human history: during the East Asian economic miracles. In no small words, Cowen states that the economic successes of these countries represent “the highest manifestation of the ethical good in human history to date.” Here is a look at four countries that embody this miracle:

While their histories and economic trajectories are unique, these countries underwent an unprecedented transformation in living standards in a roughly 40 year span. These countries stand today among the most developed and economically vibrant nations in the world, and are for many true symbols of the power of economic growth and its capacity to bring prosperity to society.

How Do We Sustain Growth?

Looking at these charts for me drives home the benefits of growth, both for the United States and other countries. Of course, a few line charts can only scratch the surface of what economic growth can do to people’s wellbeing. The consequences of high economic growth cannot be understated, but should also not be taken for granted. The world would be in a worse spot if the American economy grew at a lower rate than it had…but we could also be in a much better place if it had been higher. These graphs help us visualize where we could be, and where we have to go.

The economist Robert E Lucas said: “The consequences for human welfare involved in questions like these are staggering: once one starts to think about [exponential growth], it is hard to think about anything else”. Still, there are different theories of how to reach ambitious but sustainable growth. I plan to write another blog post that highlights these theories.

One that I find convincing is that we should again prioritize the material world over the digital world if we want to reach the economic growth rates we once had. Another is that we should free up discretionary spending in the federal budget, and prioritize investment (in education, infrastructure, medical research) over fixed spending (in Medicare/Medicaid). It is also useful to look at times in US history, as well as in the history of other countries, when policy-makers sacrificed short term pain for long-term benefit. Some examples that come to mind are lifting domestic airline regulations in the US, committing to liberalizing trade and large-scale privatization as part of the Balcerowicz Plan in post-communist Poland, and unleashing the freedom of mobility by liberalizing the hukou system in China.

A moral commitment to the future goes against many of our innate impulses as humans. Yet our inability to put ourselves in the shoes of someone who will live in the distant future is exactly the bias we need to check if we our to ensure that our progeny will live in a stable world. If we can make this leap — a leap of both faith and imagination — we will give more attention to our actions, knowing others will have to live in the world that we’ve wrought.